Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 73 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 74 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Warning (512): Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853 [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48]Code Contextif (Configure::read('debug')) {
trigger_error($message, E_USER_WARNING);
} else {
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => '&#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo; </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 15805, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | &#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'metaKeywords' => 'Governance', 'metaDesc' => ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo;</div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => '&#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo; </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 15805 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | &#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan' $metaKeywords = 'Governance' $metaDesc = ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo;</div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | 'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, <a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">“The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s”</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?”</div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $maxBufferLength = (int) 8192 $file = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php' $line = (int) 853 $message = 'Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853'Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148]Code Context$response->getStatusCode(),
($reasonPhrase ? ' ' . $reasonPhrase : '')
));
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => '&#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo; </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 15805, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | &#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'metaKeywords' => 'Governance', 'metaDesc' => ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo;</div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => '&#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo; </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 15805 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | &#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan' $metaKeywords = 'Governance' $metaDesc = ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo;</div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | 'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, <a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">“The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s”</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?”</div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $reasonPhrase = 'OK'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitStatusLine() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 54 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181]Notice (8): Undefined variable: urlPrefix [APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8]Code Context$value
), $first);
$first = false;
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr68133a26bb50c-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => '&#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo; </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 15805, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | &#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'metaKeywords' => 'Governance', 'metaDesc' => ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo;</div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => '&#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo; </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 15805 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | &#039;Reforms&#039; for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan' $metaKeywords = 'Governance' $metaDesc = ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo;. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don&rsquo;t declare unswerving support for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope&rsquo;s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 &ldquo;propositions&rdquo; to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant &ldquo;Reformation&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word &ldquo;reform&rdquo; to their names. Thus, there was the &ldquo;Penal Reform League&rdquo;, the &ldquo;Electoral Reform Society&rdquo; and in 1832 even &ldquo;the Great Reform Act&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as &ldquo;make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: &ldquo;reform&rdquo; as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, &ldquo;banking sector reforms&rdquo; in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo;, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the &ldquo;banking reform&rdquo; under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put &ldquo;new heightened capital and leverage limits&rdquo; on big banks, &ldquo;instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank&rsquo;s lending programs&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does &ldquo;reform&rdquo; mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, &ldquo;labour reforms&rdquo; in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a &ldquo;reform&rdquo; of one era could result in a situation that requires &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 &ldquo;banking reforms&rdquo; recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for &ldquo;reform&rdquo; for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for &ldquo;financial reform&rdquo; in the economy but resist &ldquo;stock exchange reforms&rdquo;. So strong was the brokers&rsquo; resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper,&nbsp;<a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&amp;context=peri_workingpapers&amp;sei-redir=1&amp;referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">&ldquo;The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s&rdquo;</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of &ldquo;reforms&rdquo; and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=&ldquo;reforms&rdquo;) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, &ldquo;the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD&rsquo;s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes&rdquo;.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for &ldquo;reform&rdquo;, it might be useful to ask, &ldquo;For whose benefit is this reform?&rdquo;</div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | 'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, <a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">“The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s”</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?”</div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $cookies = [] $values = [ (int) 0 => 'text/html; charset=UTF-8' ] $name = 'Content-Type' $first = true $value = 'text/html; charset=UTF-8'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitHeaders() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 55 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
<head>
<link rel="canonical" href="<?php echo Configure::read('SITE_URL'); ?><?php echo $urlPrefix;?><?php echo $article_current->category->slug; ?>/<?php echo $article_current->seo_url; ?>.html"/>
<meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/>
$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => ''Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, <a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">“The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms”</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?” </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 15805, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | 'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'metaKeywords' => 'Governance', 'metaDesc' => ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, <a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">“The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s”</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?”</div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 15805, 'title' => ''Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, <a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">“The Social Construction of Successful Market Reforms”</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?” </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Business Standard, 28 June, 2012, http://www.business-standard.com/india/news/ajit-balakrishnan-reforms-for-whom/478668/', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => '039reforms039-for-whom-ajit-balakrishnan-15932', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 15932, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 15805 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | 'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan' $metaKeywords = 'Governance' $metaDesc = ' Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms'</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, <a href="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22" title="http://scholarworks.umass.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1168&context=peri_workingpapers&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.google.co.in%2Furl%3Fsa%3Dt%26rct%3Dj%26q%3Dthe%2520social%2520construction%2520of%2520successful%2520market%2520reforms%25E2%2580%259D%252C%2520oxford%2520university%2520sociologist%2520david%2520stuckler%26source%3Dweb%26cd%3D1%26sqi%3D2%26ved%3D0CE4QFjAA%26url%3Dhttp%253A%252F%252Fscholarworks.umass.edu%252Fcgi%252Fviewcontent.cgi%253Farticle%253D1168%2526context%253Dperi_workingpapers%26ei%3DWALsT7zGFZGHrAf8hrTOBQ%26usg%3DAFQjCNEvQeNtHTHZm9oMafAfbSD_3Wi0DQ#search=%22social%20construction%20successful%20market%20reforms%E2%80%9D%2C%20oxford%20university%20sociologist%20david%20stuckler%22">“The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform<br />s”</a>, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?”</div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'
include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51
![]() |
'Reforms' for whom?-Ajit Balakrishnan |
Two ways to advertise your modernity in India today: first is to carry an iPad, second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of 'reforms' There are two quick ways to advertise your modernity in India today. The first is to carry an iPad when you go for meetings, even if all you do with it is read email; and the second is to declare that you are firmly on the side of “reforms”. As a corollary, you must also declare that only more “reforms” will arrest our falling economic growth rate and revive the wilting rupee and the Sensex. Conversely, if you don not carry an iPad to a meeting and don’t declare unswerving support for “reform”, you are out of touch. This positive connotation for “reform” probably dates back to October 31, 1517, when Martin Luther, distressed by the Pope’s practice of charging a price for forgiving sinners, nailed his 95 “propositions” to the door of a church in Wittenberg, sparking off the Protestant “Reformation”. This positive slant to the word (at least in the non-Catholic countries) was further reinforced during the 19th century in England when various groups lobbying for causes such as improved working conditions, universal voting rights and so on started appending the word “reform” to their names. Thus, there was the “Penal Reform League”, the “Electoral Reform Society” and in 1832 even “the Great Reform Act”. The Oxford English Dictionary has stamped its approval on the word by defining “reform” as “make changes in (something, especially an institution or practice) in order to improve it”. In recent times, another shade of meaning has got loaded onto the word: “reform” as an action that lets market forces set the prices of goods and services as well as interest rates. Conversely, it means having the state play a lesser role in economic affairs. Thus, “banking sector reforms” in India have come to mean allowing more private sector banks to set up shop and letting the market, not the Reserve Bank of India, set interest rates. In other words, it means giving banks more freedom to operate. What is puzzling, though, is that in the US today “banking reform” has exactly the opposite meaning to what it has in India. When American media and policy makers talk of “banking reform”, they mean putting more controls on banks. Thus, the “banking reform” under way there currently, according to The Wall Street Journal, will put “new heightened capital and leverage limits” on big banks, “instructs the government to conduct unprecedented, ongoing audits of the central bank’s lending programs”. Not only does “reform” mean different things in different countries, it may also mean different things in the same country at different points of time. For instance, “labour reforms” in the 1950s in India generally meant giving workers the right to form unions. Today, however, they mean the opposite: giving employers greater flexibility in hiring and firing workers. It is also useful to remember that a “reform” of one era could result in a situation that requires “reforms” of another era to be undone. For example, the general sentiment in the 1960s was that Indian banks were too cosy with business groups that owned and controlled them, and were not risk-taking enough in opening branches and lending to new entrepreneurs. These sentiments, in the course of time, led to the nationalisation in 1969 of 14 of the largest banks, which were then pushed to expand. By 1990, deposits had increased eightfold to Rs 1.1 lakh crore and the number of branches tenfold to 60,000. But this heady expansion also created non-performing assets and hidden losses on their balance sheets. Voila! The 1991 “banking reforms” recapitalised these banks, with the government pumping money. You can also set different standards for “reform” for yourself and for others. Thus, the stockbrokers on the Bombay Stock Exchange are always in the forefront of calls for “financial reform” in the economy but resist “stock exchange reforms”. So strong was the brokers’ resistance to, for example, computerisation that the government had to set up a parallel stock exchange, the National Stock Exchange, to get it done. The success or failure of reforms can also be invented. In their recent working paper, “The Social Construction of Successful Market Reform s”, Oxford University sociologist David Stuckler and the co-authors say that the success of “reforms” and the statistics to prove that they are successful are socially constructed by motivated actors such as the bureaucrats in agencies that ran their programmes and players in the financial services industries. For instance, the extensive statistics published by the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) about the East European experience in the 1990s are the basis of the belief that large-scale privatisation (=“reforms”) leads to rapid economic growth. But when the authors re-examined the same data, “the positive growth effect of large-scale privatisation disappears ... [suggesting] that many cross-national studies using the EBRD’s statistics have potentially substantially overstated the links between neo-liberal reforms and positive outcomes”. The next time you hear a call for “reform”, it might be useful to ask, “For whose benefit is this reform?”
|