Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 73 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 74 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Warning (512): Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853 [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48]Code Contextif (Configure::read('debug')) {
trigger_error($message, E_USER_WARNING);
} else {
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 18379, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'metaKeywords' => 'Economic Reforms,Growth', 'metaDesc' => ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 18379 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta' $metaKeywords = 'Economic Reforms,Growth' $metaDesc = ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’ </em></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $maxBufferLength = (int) 8192 $file = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php' $line = (int) 853 $message = 'Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853'Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148]Code Context$response->getStatusCode(),
($reasonPhrase ? ' ' . $reasonPhrase : '')
));
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 18379, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'metaKeywords' => 'Economic Reforms,Growth', 'metaDesc' => ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 18379 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta' $metaKeywords = 'Economic Reforms,Growth' $metaDesc = ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’ </em></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $reasonPhrase = 'OK'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitStatusLine() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 54 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181]Notice (8): Undefined variable: urlPrefix [APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8]Code Context$value
), $first);
$first = false;
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67f2c39d35db1-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 18379, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'metaKeywords' => 'Economic Reforms,Growth', 'metaDesc' => ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 18379 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta' $metaKeywords = 'Economic Reforms,Growth' $metaDesc = ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence&rsquo;s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India&rsquo;s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don&rsquo;t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister&rsquo;s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like &ldquo;supply side constraints&rdquo;. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, &lsquo;The Indian Express&rsquo;&nbsp;</em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’ </em></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $cookies = [] $values = [ (int) 0 => 'text/html; charset=UTF-8' ] $name = 'Content-Type' $first = true $value = 'text/html; charset=UTF-8'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitHeaders() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 55 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
<head>
<link rel="canonical" href="<?php echo Configure::read('SITE_URL'); ?><?php echo $urlPrefix;?><?php echo $article_current->category->slug; ?>/<?php echo $article_current->seo_url; ?>.html"/>
<meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/>
$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’ </em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 18379, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'metaKeywords' => 'Economic Reforms,Growth', 'metaDesc' => ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’ </em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 18379, 'title' => 'Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> -The Indian Express </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’ </em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Indian Express, 12 December, 2012, http://www.indianexpress.com/news/myths-of-our-making/1043870/0', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'myths-of-our-making-pratap-bhanu-mehta-18508', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 18508, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 18379 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta' $metaKeywords = 'Economic Reforms,Growth' $metaDesc = ' -The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify">-The Indian Express</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths</em></div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around?</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify"><em>The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’ </em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'
include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51
![]() |
Myths of our making-Pratap Bhanu Mehta |
-The Indian Express Too many of our economic prescriptions are based on dogma, empirical half-truths It has become fashionable to say, following the conclusions of Michael Spence’s Growth Commission, that there is no single recipe for growth, only some common ingredients. Such a claim brings a due degree of modesty to what we do or do not know about growth. And at the very least, such a claim has the virtue of jolting us out of fatalism: there are no iron laws explaining success or failure. Lots of causal variables that we intuitively think matter, like education, political stability, good institutions or infrastructure, often turn out to be as much effects as the cause of growth. Lots of conjunctural variables like geo-strategic rents or global circumstances matter. And the one thing we have learnt over the last few years is that the causal correlation between any two variables is highly contingent; it depends on the circumstances. How much do interest rates affect growth? How much does decline in growth rates affect inflation? What is the relationship between agriculture wages and productivity? Many of the challenges of growth are about figuring our way through these kinds of relationships. Nothing can kill an economy better than a dogma or empirical half-truths masquerading as certainty. Much of the public discussion about the economy is in a bit of an intellectual limbo. Some of this discussion is an artefact of noise: many bad arguments drive out good ones. Some a product of inevitable ideological differences: in the face of uncertainty, retreat to your simple convictions. Even in academic circles in India, there is more debate than dialogue. The former is oriented to cutting down arguments; the latter to figuring things out. There is a lot of extraordinarily good work in economics. Several were heroically warning against dangers that lie ahead. Nevertheless, with hindsight it has to be said that our political complacency about growth was legitimised by intellectual complacency. The stories we told, or failed to tell, have been as responsible for inducing complacency as political paralysis. It is often the economy, stupid. But behind the economy is a myth. Think of the mystifications that did us incalculable damage over the last few years. The first was the so-called soundness of India’s banking sector. We patted ourselves on the back for surviving the global financial crisis without a banking meltdown. It turned out that we had a banking crisis of our own, with public sector banks recklessly concentrating credit and not taking political risks into account. And there is still no clear assessment of just how good Indian banks are at allocating credit, and how much of a constraint this will be on growth. God forbid there should be another crisis. But will you believe the government about the soundness of the banking system as easily as you did the last time around? The second was the mystification that fiscal deficits either don’t matter or will be self-correcting. Now, the degree of deficit we can sustain is something to be carefully debated. But it is an astonishing fact that (a few exceptions apart) much of the official economics establishment, including the Prime Minister’s Economic Advisory Council, stayed silent, for all practical purposes, on the issue. Given that economies are, in part, confidence tricks, governments will understandably minimise downside risks. But it is still something of a mystery why it took a Kelkar from the outside to raise the alarm bells on how much of a soup we were in. The quality of economists in the establishment may be high, but the credibility of the system as a whole took a hit. And now we are in the awkward position of having to reduce deficits when growth is slowing. The third mystification was about inflation. Again, with a few exceptions, we kept pumping up the idea that inflation was largely about interest rates. We would rather place the RBI in the middle of what was largely an ideological tug-of-war than get to the bottom of the stickiness of inflation. Much of the debate on inflation had an a priori cast to it, with slogans even most non-economists could parrot, like “supply side constraints”. But which ones mattered more and why? There were several intriguing hypotheses that were never fully examined. Harish Damodaran had been heroically arguing that rural wages are stickier now. In the past, lowering inflation used to be on the backs of lowering wages of rural poor. This is no longer possible. In welfare terms, this may be a good thing, but it means prices are stickier. Urjit Patel argued that the wealth effects of gold were such that people did not reduce consumption as predicted; other argued that asset prices like land were the principal cause, and still others argued, with some justification, that we did not have accurate enough data to say anything half reliable. But the certainty of prescriptions did not reflect the underlying tentativeness. The fourth mystification was around manufacturing. India sensed rightly that it may not need to follow a conventional path in terms of manufacturing. But this plausible insight induced an extraordinary hubris, where we simply forgot to ask fundamental questions like: Can the rate of service exports keep up with the import bill if the demand for manufactured goods explodes? In short, will you always be at risk of running a current account deficit if you do not have a diversified manufacturing base? Second, what are the opportunity costs of not leveraging growing domestic demand to give domestic manufacturing a boost? To be fair, a manufacturing policy has been high on the discussion agenda. But most of what passes off as policy is old wishful thinking: it confuses manufacturing policy for a real estate policy. If only we set up enclaves here and there, problems will be solved. The nuances that go into thinking about the nature and character of our productivity growth are largely absent. This point is important because the fact is that industrial growth is sluggish. Even in areas where we should have more momentum, like textiles and automobiles, our advantage is slipping away. It would be catastrophic if the services dogma continues to undergird the de-industrialisation of India. Restoring vibrancy to the economy will not be just a matter of top-down reforms. It will require a contagion of energy across many different sectors. Political paralysis can stymie that energy. But so can the stories we tell ourselves. Managing an economy, particularly an open one, is less like figuring out a theory, more like managing a chess board. Unfortunately, at the moment, we are playing chess with our hands tied on more than half the squares. We keep looking for the knight, when whole armies are being decimated. The writer, president of the Centre for Policy Research, is contributing editor, ‘The Indian Express’
|