Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 73 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 74 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Warning (512): Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853 [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48]Code Contextif (Configure::read('debug')) {
trigger_error($message, E_USER_WARNING);
} else {
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&amp;Source=Page&amp;Skin=ETNEW&amp;BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&amp;PageLabel=13&amp;Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 13208, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'metaKeywords' => 'Agriculture', 'metaDesc' => ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&amp;Source=Page&amp;Skin=ETNEW&amp;BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&amp;PageLabel=13&amp;Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 13208 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy' $metaKeywords = 'Agriculture' $metaDesc = ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? </div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• 30% reduction in transportation costs. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $maxBufferLength = (int) 8192 $file = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php' $line = (int) 853 $message = 'Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853'Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148]Code Context$response->getStatusCode(),
($reasonPhrase ? ' ' . $reasonPhrase : '')
));
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&amp;Source=Page&amp;Skin=ETNEW&amp;BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&amp;PageLabel=13&amp;Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 13208, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'metaKeywords' => 'Agriculture', 'metaDesc' => ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&amp;Source=Page&amp;Skin=ETNEW&amp;BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&amp;PageLabel=13&amp;Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 13208 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy' $metaKeywords = 'Agriculture' $metaDesc = ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? </div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• 30% reduction in transportation costs. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $reasonPhrase = 'OK'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitStatusLine() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 54 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181]Notice (8): Undefined variable: urlPrefix [APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8]Code Context$value
), $first);
$first = false;
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67f0453521c1a-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&amp;Source=Page&amp;Skin=ETNEW&amp;BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&amp;PageLabel=13&amp;Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 13208, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'metaKeywords' => 'Agriculture', 'metaDesc' => ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> &bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp; </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&amp;Source=Page&amp;Skin=ETNEW&amp;BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&amp;PageLabel=13&amp;Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 13208 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy' $metaKeywords = 'Agriculture' $metaDesc = ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn&rsquo;t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions?&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn&rsquo;t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets:&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers).&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; 30% reduction in transportation costs.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">&bull; More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that&rsquo;s not the point.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, &ldquo;It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country&rsquo;s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.&rdquo; What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn&rsquo;t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn&rsquo;t mean FDI in retail shouldn&rsquo;t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can&rsquo;t address those.&nbsp;</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? </div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• 30% reduction in transportation costs. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $cookies = [] $values = [ (int) 0 => 'text/html; charset=UTF-8' ] $name = 'Content-Type' $first = true $value = 'text/html; charset=UTF-8'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitHeaders() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 55 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
<head>
<link rel="canonical" href="<?php echo Configure::read('SITE_URL'); ?><?php echo $urlPrefix;?><?php echo $article_current->category->slug; ?>/<?php echo $article_current->seo_url; ?>.html"/>
<meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/>
$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • 30% reduction in transportation costs. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&Source=Page&Skin=ETNEW&BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&PageLabel=13&Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 13208, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'metaKeywords' => 'Agriculture', 'metaDesc' => ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...', 'disp' => '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? </div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• 30% reduction in transportation costs. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 13208, 'title' => 'Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • 30% reduction in transportation costs. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> • More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) </div> <div style="text-align: justify"> <br /> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Times of India, 20 February, 2012, http://epaper.timesofindia.com/Default/Scripting/ArticleWin.asp?From=Archive&Source=Page&Skin=ETNEW&BaseHref=ETD/2012/02/20&PageLabel=13&Enti', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'policy-distortions-hurt-agriculture-by-bibek-debroy-13330', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 13330, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 13208 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy' $metaKeywords = 'Agriculture' $metaDesc = ' Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against...' $disp = '<div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? </div><div style="text-align: justify"> </div><div style="text-align: justify">To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• 30% reduction in transportation costs. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken.</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">• More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. </div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div><div style="text-align: justify">(The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research)</div><div style="text-align: justify"><br /></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'
include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51
![]() |
Policy Distortions Hurt Agriculture by Bibek Debroy |
Food price inflation, and inflation in general, has become less of an issue. But it isn’t an issue that will go away. Give it till June and inflation is likely to inch up again. Competition is a good antidote against price increases. It ensures efficiency and reduces price volatility. Logically, food price inflation should trigger and stimulate agricultural reform, so there is competition and supply-side changes can occur. But in practice, it often leads to greater distortions and state intervention, at least in short term. What is the core issue? That is one of investing in agriculture and rural sector and injecting competition into market access by farmers, reducing intermediation. But the point is that government policies often prevent this. In output markets, producer price controls exist in several developing countries. Triggered by food price increases, across a range of countries, there have been interventions on consumption side, including price controls, consumption subsidies, food aid, food for work, cash transfers and elimination of taxes on consumption. Are these fiscally sustainable? Do they lead to additional distortions? Do they lead to supply-side adjustments or are they knee-jerk reactions? To take but one example, in several countries, minimum support prices (MSPs) for agricultural commodities have been increased. Apart from contributing to food price inflation, this increases spread between prices paid to producers and subsidised prices charged to consumers, increasing the fiscal burden. Since MSPs need not always extend to all agricultural commodities and public procurement need not cover all commodities either, this creates perverse price signals and distorts resource allocation. Just because other countries have introduced knee-jerk reactions, that doesn’t mean they are rational. The proposed Food Security Bill needs to be considered against that backdrop. A Commission on Centre-State relations, set up on this, submitted a report in 2010. One of the sub-reports focused on lack of harmonised domestic market in agricultural products. This sub-report has the following kind of numbers from unification and harmonisation of agricultural markets: • Reduction of post-harvest losses by 5-7% for grains and 25-30% for fruit and vegetables. • Static gains of 10% through harmonising standards of farm products across states. • Static efficiency gains of up to 20% because of disintermediation of distribution chains, resulting in higher prices for farmers and lower prices paid by consumers (welfare gains are roughly distributed in a ratio of 40% for farmers and 60% for consumers). • Savings in compliance costs by 5% after fiscal unification. • Savings of up to 20% if there is a transition to a complete and unified GST and revenue gains of 25%. • Increase in tax/GDP ratio by 1%. • 30% reduction in transportation costs. • Incremental growth in agriculture and allied activities by 2% because of static gains. • Static increment to GDP growth by 1% because of removal of inter-state barriers alone. • Increment by 2% if broader agricultural-cum-rural sector reforms are undertaken. • Increase in export volume (not value) of agricultural products by 20%. • More direct employment generation by five million a year. If one includes indirect employment, additional employment generation rises by 12 million a year. One can quibble about modelling used or specific numbers in this sub-report. But that’s not the point. A Draft National Competition Policy has now been prepared. This states, “It has been observed that certain policies and laws at the state level sometimes tend to artificially segment markets in India. Policies and/or laws, which interface with a large section of the country’s population, such as agriculture, power, etc, may erode substantial benefits potentially emanating from a national market and the presence of competition across all sectors.” What are these policy-induced distortions? First, there are physical government-imposed restrictions on production, marketing and distribution. These are usually through Essential Commodities Act (ECA), and its orders. Second, there are MSPs and procurement policies in favour of food grains. Third, there are the APMC Acts. Stated simply, APMC Acts require buying and selling of agricultural products to be done through regulated markets, with mandated fees to be paid to market committees. Fourth, there is a lack of harmonisation of indirect taxes on agricultural products across states. Fifth, because of ECA, APMC and fiscal anomalies, there are physical checkposts, which are particularly serious for perishable agricultural produce. In addition, there are physical checks on trucks thanks to environment-related laws like Indian Forests Act, Forest (Conservation) Act and Rules, Air (Prevention and Control of Pollution) Act and Rules, Manufacture, Use, Import, Export and Storage of Hazardous Microorganisms/Genetically Engineered Organisms or Cells Rules, Wildlife Protection Act and Rules and Biomedical Waste (Management and Handling Rules) and lack of uniformity under Motor Vehicles Act and its assorted rules. The problem is with multiplicity, rather than clearances per se. That list is only for output markets. But competition in agriculture isn’t only about the farm-to-fork supply chain, it is also about input markets. Seeds, pesticides, agrochemicals and fertilisers are obvious examples. Power and water belong to a slightly different category. In each, there are policyinduced distortions. Some argue FDI in multi-brand retail will solve supply-side problems, reduce intermediation and check food prices. FDI in retail is a small part of the jigsaw. It will be a disaster to claim this is a magic wand. It doesn’t mean FDI in retail shouldn’t be opened up. But there are other important anti-competitive policies and one latches on to FDI because one can’t address those. (The author is professor at the Centre for Policy Research) |