Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 73 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 73, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'catslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 73 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]Code Context
trigger_error($message, E_USER_DEPRECATED);
}
$message = 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 74 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php.' $stackFrame = (int) 1 $trace = [ (int) 0 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ServerRequest.php', 'line' => (int) 2421, 'function' => 'deprecationWarning', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead.' ] ], (int) 1 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ], (int) 2 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Controller/Controller.php', 'line' => (int) 610, 'function' => 'printArticle', 'class' => 'App\Controller\ArtileDetailController', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 3 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 120, 'function' => 'invokeAction', 'class' => 'Cake\Controller\Controller', 'object' => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ], (int) 4 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php', 'line' => (int) 94, 'function' => '_invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(App\Controller\ArtileDetailController) {} ] ], (int) 5 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/BaseApplication.php', 'line' => (int) 235, 'function' => 'dispatch', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 6 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\BaseApplication', 'object' => object(App\Application) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 7 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 162, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 8 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 9 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 88, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 10 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 11 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php', 'line' => (int) 96, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 12 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 65, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware', 'object' => object(Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {} ] ], (int) 13 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Runner.php', 'line' => (int) 51, 'function' => '__invoke', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 14 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Http/Server.php', 'line' => (int) 98, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Runner', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Runner) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\Http\MiddlewareQueue) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) {}, (int) 2 => object(Cake\Http\Response) {} ] ], (int) 15 => [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/webroot/index.php', 'line' => (int) 39, 'function' => 'run', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\Server', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\Server) {}, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [] ] ] $frame = [ 'file' => '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php', 'line' => (int) 74, 'function' => 'offsetGet', 'class' => 'Cake\Http\ServerRequest', 'object' => object(Cake\Http\ServerRequest) { trustProxy => false [protected] params => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] data => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] query => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] cookies => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _environment => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] url => 'latest-news-updates/undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756/print' [protected] base => '' [protected] webroot => '/' [protected] here => '/latest-news-updates/undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756/print' [protected] trustedProxies => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] _input => null [protected] _detectors => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] _detectorCache => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] stream => object(Zend\Diactoros\PhpInputStream) {} [protected] uri => object(Zend\Diactoros\Uri) {} [protected] session => object(Cake\Http\Session) {} [protected] attributes => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] emulatedAttributes => [ [maximum depth reached] ] [protected] uploadedFiles => [[maximum depth reached]] [protected] protocol => null [protected] requestTarget => null [private] deprecatedProperties => [ [maximum depth reached] ] }, 'type' => '->', 'args' => [ (int) 0 => 'artileslug' ] ]deprecationWarning - CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311 Cake\Http\ServerRequest::offsetGet() - CORE/src/Http/ServerRequest.php, line 2421 App\Controller\ArtileDetailController::printArticle() - APP/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line 74 Cake\Controller\Controller::invokeAction() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 610 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 120 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51 Cake\Http\Server::run() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 98
Warning (512): Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853 [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48]Code Contextif (Configure::read('debug')) {
trigger_error($message, E_USER_WARNING);
} else {
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 7658, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'metaKeywords' => 'NREGS,Malnutrition', 'metaDesc' => ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...', 'disp' => '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 7658 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey' $metaKeywords = 'NREGS,Malnutrition' $metaDesc = ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...' $disp = '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $maxBufferLength = (int) 8192 $file = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php' $line = (int) 853 $message = 'Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853'Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148]Code Context$response->getStatusCode(),
($reasonPhrase ? ' ' . $reasonPhrase : '')
));
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 7658, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'metaKeywords' => 'NREGS,Malnutrition', 'metaDesc' => ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...', 'disp' => '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 7658 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey' $metaKeywords = 'NREGS,Malnutrition' $metaDesc = ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...' $disp = '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $reasonPhrase = 'OK'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitStatusLine() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 54 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181]Notice (8): Undefined variable: urlPrefix [APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8]Code Context$value
), $first);
$first = false;
$response = object(Cake\Http\Response) { 'status' => (int) 200, 'contentType' => 'text/html', 'headers' => [ 'Content-Type' => [ [maximum depth reached] ] ], 'file' => null, 'fileRange' => [], 'cookies' => object(Cake\Http\Cookie\CookieCollection) {}, 'cacheDirectives' => [], 'body' => '<!DOCTYPE html PUBLIC "-//W3C//DTD XHTML 1.0 Transitional//EN" "http://www.w3.org/TR/xhtml1/DTD/xhtml1-transitional.dtd"> <html xmlns="http://www.w3.org/1999/xhtml"> <head> <link rel="canonical" href="https://im4change.in/<pre class="cake-error"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none');"><b>Notice</b> (8)</a>: Undefined variable: urlPrefix [<b>APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp</b>, line <b>8</b>]<div id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-trace" class="cake-stack-trace" style="display: none;"><a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Code</a> <a href="javascript:void(0);" onclick="document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context').style.display = (document.getElementById('cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context').style.display == 'none' ? '' : 'none')">Context</a><pre id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-code" class="cake-code-dump" style="display: none;"><code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"></span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">head</span><span style="color: #007700">> </span></span></code> <span class="code-highlight"><code><span style="color: #000000"> <link rel="canonical" href="<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">Configure</span><span style="color: #007700">::</span><span style="color: #0000BB">read</span><span style="color: #007700">(</span><span style="color: #DD0000">'SITE_URL'</span><span style="color: #007700">); </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$urlPrefix</span><span style="color: #007700">;</span><span style="color: #0000BB">?><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">category</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">slug</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>/<span style="color: #0000BB"><?php </span><span style="color: #007700">echo </span><span style="color: #0000BB">$article_current</span><span style="color: #007700">-></span><span style="color: #0000BB">seo_url</span><span style="color: #007700">; </span><span style="color: #0000BB">?></span>.html"/> </span></code></span> <code><span style="color: #000000"><span style="color: #0000BB"> </span><span style="color: #007700"><</span><span style="color: #0000BB">meta http</span><span style="color: #007700">-</span><span style="color: #0000BB">equiv</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"Content-Type" </span><span style="color: #0000BB">content</span><span style="color: #007700">=</span><span style="color: #DD0000">"text/html; charset=utf-8"</span><span style="color: #007700">/> </span></span></code></pre><pre id="cakeErr67ef0a49d8b48-context" class="cake-context" style="display: none;">$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 7658, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'metaKeywords' => 'NREGS,Malnutrition', 'metaDesc' => ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...', 'disp' => '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 7658 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey' $metaKeywords = 'NREGS,Malnutrition' $metaDesc = ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...' $disp = '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (&gt; Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'</pre><pre class="stack-trace">include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51</pre></div></pre>latest-news-updates/undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756.html"/> <meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/> <link href="https://im4change.in/css/control.css" rel="stylesheet" type="text/css" media="all"/> <title>LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey | Im4change.org</title> <meta name="description" content=" In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former..."/> <script src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-1.10.2.js"></script> <script type="text/javascript" src="https://im4change.in/js/jquery-migrate.min.js"></script> <script language="javascript" type="text/javascript"> $(document).ready(function () { var img = $("img")[0]; // Get my img elem var pic_real_width, pic_real_height; $("<img/>") // Make in memory copy of image to avoid css issues .attr("src", $(img).attr("src")) .load(function () { pic_real_width = this.width; // Note: $(this).width() will not pic_real_height = this.height; // work for in memory images. }); }); </script> <style type="text/css"> @media screen { div.divFooter { display: block; } } @media print { .printbutton { display: none !important; } } </style> </head> <body> <table cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" border="0" width="98%" align="center"> <tr> <td class="top_bg"> <div class="divFooter"> <img src="https://im4change.in/images/logo1.jpg" height="59" border="0" alt="Resource centre on India's rural distress" style="padding-top:14px;"/> </div> </td> </tr> <tr> <td id="topspace"> </td> </tr> <tr id="topspace"> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-bottom:1px solid #000; padding-top:10px;" class="printbutton"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%"> <h1 class="news_headlines" style="font-style:normal"> <strong>Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey</strong></h1> </td> </tr> <tr> <td width="100%" style="font-family:Arial, 'Segoe Script', 'Segoe UI', sans-serif, serif"><font size="3"> <div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div> </font> </td> </tr> <tr> <td> </td> </tr> <tr> <td height="50" style="border-top:1px solid #000; border-bottom:1px solid #000;padding-top:10px;"> <form><input type="button" value=" Print this page " onclick="window.print();return false;"/></form> </td> </tr> </table></body> </html>' } $cookies = [] $values = [ (int) 0 => 'text/html; charset=UTF-8' ] $name = 'Content-Type' $first = true $value = 'text/html; charset=UTF-8'header - [internal], line ?? Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emitHeaders() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181 Cake\Http\ResponseEmitter::emit() - CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 55 Cake\Http\Server::emit() - CORE/src/Http/Server.php, line 141 [main] - ROOT/webroot/index.php, line 39
<head>
<link rel="canonical" href="<?php echo Configure::read('SITE_URL'); ?><?php echo $urlPrefix;?><?php echo $article_current->category->slug; ?>/<?php echo $article_current->seo_url; ?>.html"/>
<meta http-equiv="Content-Type" content="text/html; charset=utf-8"/>
$viewFile = '/home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp' $dataForView = [ 'article_current' => object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ [maximum depth reached] ], '[dirty]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[original]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[virtual]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[invalid]' => [[maximum depth reached]], '[repository]' => 'Articles' }, 'articleid' => (int) 7658, 'metaTitle' => 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'metaKeywords' => 'NREGS,Malnutrition', 'metaDesc' => ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...', 'disp' => '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>', 'lang' => 'English', 'SITE_URL' => 'https://im4change.in/', 'site_title' => 'im4change', 'adminprix' => 'admin' ] $article_current = object(App\Model\Entity\Article) { 'id' => (int) 7658, 'title' => 'Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey', 'subheading' => '', 'description' => '<div align="justify"> In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /> <br /> While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /> <br /> Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /> <br /> In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /> <br /> NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /> <br /> As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /> <br /> Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /> <br /> Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /> <br /> If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /> <br /> The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /> <br /> In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /> <br /> Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /> <br /> While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /> <br /> The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /> <br /> <em><br /> (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em> </div>', 'credit_writer' => 'The Economic Times, 17 May, 2011, http://economictimes.indiatimes.com/opinion/guest-writer/undernutrition-poverty-nregs/articleshow/8382606.cms', 'article_img' => '', 'article_img_thumb' => '', 'status' => (int) 1, 'show_on_home' => (int) 1, 'lang' => 'EN', 'category_id' => (int) 16, 'tag_keyword' => '', 'seo_url' => 'undernutrition-poverty-nregs-by-raghbendra-jha-raghav-gaiha-manoj-k-pandey-7756', 'meta_title' => null, 'meta_keywords' => null, 'meta_description' => null, 'noindex' => (int) 0, 'publish_date' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenDate) {}, 'most_visit_section_id' => null, 'article_big_img' => null, 'liveid' => (int) 7756, 'created' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'modified' => object(Cake\I18n\FrozenTime) {}, 'edate' => '', 'tags' => [ (int) 0 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {}, (int) 1 => object(Cake\ORM\Entity) {} ], 'category' => object(App\Model\Entity\Category) {}, '[new]' => false, '[accessible]' => [ '*' => true, 'id' => false ], '[dirty]' => [], '[original]' => [], '[virtual]' => [], '[hasErrors]' => false, '[errors]' => [], '[invalid]' => [], '[repository]' => 'Articles' } $articleid = (int) 7658 $metaTitle = 'LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey' $metaKeywords = 'NREGS,Malnutrition' $metaDesc = ' In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked. While the former...' $disp = '<div align="justify">In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.<br /><br />While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes.<br /><br />Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause.<br /><br />In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina.<br /><br />NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10.<br /><br />As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight.<br /><br />Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate.<br /><br />Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished.<br /><br />If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'.<br /><br />The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more.<br /><br />In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant).<br /><br />Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak.<br /><br />While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better.<br /><br />The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism.<br /><br /><em><br />(Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU)</em></div>' $lang = 'English' $SITE_URL = 'https://im4change.in/' $site_title = 'im4change' $adminprix = 'admin'
include - APP/Template/Layout/printlayout.ctp, line 8 Cake\View\View::_evaluate() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1413 Cake\View\View::_render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 1374 Cake\View\View::renderLayout() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 927 Cake\View\View::render() - CORE/src/View/View.php, line 885 Cake\Controller\Controller::render() - CORE/src/Controller/Controller.php, line 791 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::_invoke() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 126 Cake\Http\ActionDispatcher::dispatch() - CORE/src/Http/ActionDispatcher.php, line 94 Cake\Http\BaseApplication::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/BaseApplication.php, line 235 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\RoutingMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/RoutingMiddleware.php, line 162 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Routing\Middleware\AssetMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Routing/Middleware/AssetMiddleware.php, line 88 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Error\Middleware\ErrorHandlerMiddleware::__invoke() - CORE/src/Error/Middleware/ErrorHandlerMiddleware.php, line 96 Cake\Http\Runner::__invoke() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 65 Cake\Http\Runner::run() - CORE/src/Http/Runner.php, line 51
![]() |
Undernutrition, poverty & NREGS by Raghbendra Jha, Raghav Gaiha & Manoj K Pandey |
In the hue and cry over minimum wages under NREGS, battle lines have been drawn between those who favour central government hiking minimum wage rates to the state minimum, and others asserting that the two must be delinked.
While the former invoke 'a right to livelihood', the latter point to the NREGS being 'the employer of the last resort and the imperative of better targeting'. While these views have some merit, both sides seem to gloss over why benefits to the poor remain so low despite frequent wage hikes. Our analysis, for example, shows that (net) transfer benefits under NREGS (net of opportunity cost of time)/ household income were barely over 7% in Maharashtra, about 10% in Rajasthan and under 17% in Andhra Pradesh. The roots of the malady lie in its design and implementation aberrations. Undernutrition is not just an effect of poverty but also its cause. In an agrarian economy with surplus labour and efficiency wages, nutrition-poverty traps tend to exclude the undernourished from remunerative employment and perpetuate their poverty. Rationing of employment favours those with physical dexterity and stamina. NSS and NCAER agricultural wage and employment data over 1993-94 to 2004-05 reveal a grim story of pervasiveness of nutritionpoverty traps that foreclose an easy exit from poverty. Does this reasoning apply to NREGS? Our research (including that with Shylashri Shankar of CPR, Delhi) confirms that the undernourished were less likely to participate in it, work for long spells and earn substantial amounts. These findings are based on a survey of about 500 households in Rajasthan in 2009-10. As the work under this scheme is physically strenuous and (mostly) a piecerate system - analogous to efficiency wages - is used to determine wages, those endowed with greater stamina and dexterity have a clear advantage. Using the body mass index (BMI) as a nutritional criterion, the individuals are classified into underweight, normal and overweight. Cross-classifying them by poverty status - acutely poor, moderately poor, moderately non-poor and others - the proportion of underweight fell while that of normal rose across these groups. More generally, the BMI rose with income/expenditure but at a diminishing rate. Over 81% of the male and about 71% of the female participants in NREGS were normal while most of the remaining were underweight. Our analysis shows that the higher the NREGS wage relative to agricultural wage rate at the village level, the higher was the participation rate and correspondingly the share of normal participants. Two distortions showed up consistently: one was exclusion of the poor and, related to that, of the underweight /undernourished. If these findings have general validity -similar findings of unsatisfactory targeting are obtained from surveys in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Maharashtra, and Madhya Pradesh -the NREG minimum of .100 per day is already much too high, relative to slack period market wage rate. Far too many poor and undernourished are 'crowded out'. The number of days worked in a year was considerably higher among normal participants compared to the underweight. Not just the mean number of days worked was higher among the former but also significantly higher proportions worked for 50 days or more. In a piece-rate system, the earnings are likely to be much higher for normal participants even if the days worked do not vary much. The mean earnings were, in fact, substantially higher (about Rs 3,100 per normal participant, compared with about Rs 2,700 per underweight participant). Besides, the proportions of normal participants in the upper ranges of earnings (> Rs 5,200 per annum) were considerably higher. A policy insight is that to the extent that acutely poor overlap with the underweight, as they do, their prospects of climbing out of poverty are bleak. While the piece-rate system allows flexibility to female participants, and is meant to ensure more productive employment, assessment of work is fraught with corruption and delays. Non-existent worksites and large-scale embezzlement of wages were rife in our surveys. Although a time-rate system has its own difficulties - especially high supervision costs - it is not self-evident that it would be necessarily far worse. Indeed, if supervision capacity exists, a more flexible mode of wage payments may work better. The current debate on wage hikes seems misplaced, especially when the benefits to the poor and undernourished are so small. Legislating higher wages risks greater distortions. Whatever the verdict of the Andhra Pradesh High Court, careful attention to enhancing awareness of some components of NREGS (eg, wage payments ), proper maintenance of muster rolls, and social audits may do more to transform the lives of the poor than misguided social activism. (Jha is Rajiv Gandhi Chair Professor, Australian National University (ANU); Gaiha is Professor of Public Policy, Faculty Of Management Studies, University of Delhi; and Pandey is Research Scholar, ANU) |