Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 150
 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]
Deprecated (16384): The ArrayAccess methods will be removed in 4.0.0.Use getParam(), getData() and getQuery() instead. - /home/brlfuser/public_html/src/Controller/ArtileDetailController.php, line: 151
 You can disable deprecation warnings by setting `Error.errorLevel` to `E_ALL & ~E_USER_DEPRECATED` in your config/app.php. [CORE/src/Core/functions.php, line 311]
Warning (512): Unable to emit headers. Headers sent in file=/home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php line=853 [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 48]
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 148]
Warning (2): Cannot modify header information - headers already sent by (output started at /home/brlfuser/public_html/vendor/cakephp/cakephp/src/Error/Debugger.php:853) [CORE/src/Http/ResponseEmitter.php, line 181]
LATEST NEWS UPDATES | Can benefits be tied to the vote? -Mark Schneider

Can benefits be tied to the vote? -Mark Schneider

Share this article Share this article
published Published on Jan 15, 2014   modified Modified on Jan 15, 2014
-The Hindu Business Line


Clientelism - tying benefits to political choices - cannot work because voting preferences cannot be ascertained.

Do parties and their local agents link access to government services and benefits from government welfare schemes to how voters vote, or are expected to vote?

This political strategy, which social scientists refer to as clientelism, depends on a massive investment in local leaders who collect information on voters' party preferences, vote choices and intentions, as well as which inducements will convince voters to support their party at the polls.

This strategy also importantly depends upon the credible threat of punishment when a voter is found to vote the wrong way.

Caste, weaker predictor

Clientelism and its informational requirements are at the centre of many analyses of Indian politics and the politics of other developing countries. Nonetheless, data to test this conventional wisdom is largely lacking.

Based on my evidence from rural Rajasthan, the basic ability of village council presidents, informally akin to political middlemen, is lower than this view presumes.

Three important changes to Indian democracy in recent decades should lead us to question the capacity of parties to allocate government benefits conditional on vote choice. First, India's Election Commission has become a model in the protection of the secret ballot, and voters know it.

In a preliminary survey in rural Rajasthan, respondents were unanimous in their belief in the secrecy of the ballot.

Even in Bihar, where Centre for the Study of Developing Societies (CSDS) data is available, 77 per cent of respondents in a 2010 post-poll survey said that politicians could never (50 per cent) or rarely (26.9 per cent) find out how they voted.

This means that local agents must depend on conversations, local observations, rumours and stereotypes about the party affiliations of particular jatis (sub-castes) or communities to identify voters' political preferences.

Second, we have seen a sharp increase in electoral competition across India since the 1990s. In Rajasthan, for example, incumbent parties have been removed from office in every state election for twenty years.

Finally, recent research shows that caste has become a weaker predictor of vote choice than before. This makes the task of identifying how people vote challenging.

The Rajasthan survey

How realistic is the fundamental assumption that parties - through their local politicians - can identify voters' partisan preferences?

In January 2013, I conducted a survey of 95 village council presidents (sarpanch) and 950 randomly selected voters in rural blocks across Rajasthan.

I showed each sarpanch a sheet of ten voters, which included photographs, names, and other information from the electoral rolls, and asked each to guess which party a voter would support if an election were held tomorrow. Sarpanch guesses were matched to answers voters provided by secret ballot in the voter survey.

I used the share of sarpanch guesses that matched surveyed voters' partisan preferences to yield a rate of correct guesses, which I call guessability.

Since Rajasthan is a two-party system, caste (or local jati) is predictive of vote choice, and 95 per cent of sarpanch personally knew the voters we asked them about, I expected guessability to be high.

Interestingly, I found an overall guessability rate of 64.5 per cent. To put this number in perspective, if a sarpanch guessed voters' partisan preferences randomly between Congress and BJP, guessability would be at 50 per cent.

Sarpanch exceed this; however, guessability is equal or worse relative to two other low information methods. First, I conducted a simple statistical analysis using only land holdings and caste to predict partisan preferences.

This correctly predicted partisan preferences 64.3 per cent of the time. Second, I developed a simple decision rule using publicly available CSDS polling data on the percentage of members of major castes and Muslims who supported the BJP and Congress. If, on average, a group voted at least 15 per cent more for the BJP than Congress in the 2003 and 2008 elections (or visa versa), I guessed that all voters from that group support the BJP.

Evenly split

Otherwise, members of that group are evenly split between BJP and Congress. When I apply this rule to my data, guessability is 76 per cent. It appears that sarpanch performance on guessability does not measure up to inexpensive, low-information alternatives.

The next set of issues is to consider how guessability varies across local politicians' and voters' characteristics. We might expect more educated or politically experienced sarpanch to perform better on guessability.

Interestingly, measures of education, family political connections, and tenure in the village council have no effect. There are also no distinguishable differences in aggregate guessability rates between male and female sarpanch or upper and lower-caste sarpanch.

And what about voters? Compared to scheduled castes, voters from castes that switch the party they vote for from one election to the next, namely Jats and Meenas, were hardest to guess, while the richest and poorest voters are easier to guess than those in the middle.

This is not surprising; the rich and poor tend to interact often with local politicians to seek favours or access to welfare benefits, respectively.

Secret ballot

Another important finding is that sarpanches are better at guessing the partisanship of voters in their local co-partisan network. Of course, the sarpanch is likely to routinely interact with these voters, who are likely to reveal the party they support.

These results suggest two simple kinds of logic at odds with the conventional wisdom. Local politicians perform better at guessability when voters or the groups they belong to are commonly known to be solidly partisan or when they interact routinely with them.

Why does low guessability matter for how we think about the strength of Indian democracy? First, these results indicate that the ballot is genuinely secret.

Local politicians either cannot identify voters' partisan preferences or do not attempt to because clientelism is deemed non-credible as an electoral strategy in rural Rajasthan.

This means that voters largely vote without fear of retribution, which opens up the potential for voters to hold their leaders accountable. Second, if guessability is low, should we expect benefits to be allocated as a function of individuals' votes or partisan preferences in the first place, and should local politicians have incentives to allocate benefits in this way?

Given the unpredictability of partisan preferences among those who personally know voters in their local areas, it seems that either this strategy is quite ineffective as a vote-getting strategy or it is not as prevalent as expected. We should revisit our thinking on clientelism's pervasiveness in India.

(The author is a doctoral candidate in political science at Columbia University.)


The Hindu Business Line, 13 January, 2014, http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/opinion/can-benefits-be-tied-to-the-vote/article5574065.ece?homepage=true


Related Articles

 

Write Comments

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

*

Video Archives

Archives

share on Facebook
Twitter
RSS
Feedback
Read Later

Contact Form

Please enter security code
      Close